Syngman Rhee in 1905 and later South Korea’s first
president (1948-1960). Though born into a rural family of modest means, he was
of yangban and even royal lineage
(source).
Why is mean IQ higher in East Asia than elsewhere?
Ron Unz (2013) sees the key cause in a scarcity of land and women that
continually condemned the lower classes to reproductive extinction,
particularly among the farmers who made up most of China’s population. If a
lineage remained poor for two generations in a row, it would die out and be
replaced by downwardly mobile individuals from higher up on the social ladder.
There was thus strong selection for men with enough business smarts to avoid
poverty and amass enough assets to get married and have a family.
This model of selection seems valid for the Chinese
but less so for the Koreans and the Japanese, whose strong class divisions
should have impeded upward and downward mobility. Why, then, do these two other
populations display similarly high mean IQ? As Unz (2013) notes:
Both the Japanese and the Koreans
have done remarkably well in their economic and technological advancement, and
also as small immigrant racial minorities in America and elsewhere. However,
there is no evidence that rural life in either country had any of the major features
possibly so significant for Chinese history, such as a total lack of feudal
caste structure, an exceptionally commercialized system of agricultural
production and land tenure, and the massive universal downward mobility due to
equal division of property among male heirs.
Stripped down to its basics, the Clark-Unz model of selection
has three key elements:
1. Class differences that reflect differences in
intellectual performance.
2. A higher level of reproductive success in higher
social classes than in lower ones.
3. No barriers to downward social mobility. The
lower classes are thus gradually replaced by people of higher social
origin.
But surely these three factors prevail everywhere?
No, not at all. Hunter-gatherers and simple agricultural societies have little
or no social stratification. Other societies are stratified but have no State
that can monopolize the use of violence. Upward mobility is thus an ongoing
free-for-all that selects for other psychological characteristics, i.e.,
ruthlessness, charisma, and ability to mobilize gangs of young men. Finally,
still other societies are so stratified that downward mobility is impossible.
This is the case with the caste system in India, where the shame of “losing
caste” deters downward mobility. In addition, the lowest castes can afford to
reproduce because certain stigmatized kinds of work are reserved for them, so
there is no need to replenish their ranks with people of higher social origin.
How do Japan and Korea fit into this picture? Before
the 19th century, both were feudal aristocracies where the elites monopolized
the use of violence. For the bulk of the population, there was thus little
selection for “Big Men”, as is the case in societies where State formation is
weaker. The question then remains whether Japan and Korea were caste societies.
Did the lowest classes reproduce essentially on their own? Or were they
replaced by a steady infusion of downwardly mobile individuals?
Among the Japanese lower classes, the Burakumin were
the only real caste, in the sense of a group that lost few members through
upward mobility and gained few through downward mobility. It is probably for
this reason that the Burakumin differ so much from other Japanese in terms of
behavior, personality traits, and intellectual performance. They seem to have
preserved the mental and behavioral predispositions that were dominant in the
Japanese population five hundred to a thousand years ago (see previous post).
Japan's class structure seems to have resembled
Britain's. In both cases, there were attempts to codify class differences, and
in both cases these attempts largely failed. The Britannica's description of
Japanese society in the 18th and 19th centuries sounds very much like premodern
Chinese society:
Inevitably it [commercial
development] meant the rise of some wealthy members of the rural populace, who
used their wealth to invest in land and commercial ventures and to "ape
their betters" in the cities in both custom and culture. Few farmers,
however, prospered through producing commercial goods, and the majority of
peasants remained impoverished. Rural villages were characterized by a few
wealthy farmers, a majority of small-scale independent landholders, and a
growing number of impoverished tenants. Many small-scale farmers, squeezed by
the demands of commercial development, were forced to part with their lands and
fell into tenancy. (Britannica, 1998)
A similar situation seems to have prevailed in
Korea, even though the yangban were
theoretically guaranteed a privileged status by virtue of their high birth or
success on civil service exams. Moon (1992, p. 204) describes impoverished yangban living alongside peasants and
commoners as fellow tenants. Breen (2004) likewise describes numbers of yangban sinking into poverty without
hope of gaining a government office.
The way a society works in theory often differs from
the way it actually works. English society has long been described as having
rigid class distinctions. Yet when Clark (2009) analyzed the transmission of surnames
by social class, he found evidence of considerable social mobility going back
to the Middle Ages:
Clark, for
example, denoted in the middle ages anyone performing clerical work, including
the minor orders of the clergy who were allowed to marry. Since literacy was
extremely limited in medieval England clark
was thus originally an upper class name. But by 1600 0.7 percent of the
indicted bear this surname, as many as among rich testators (0.63 percent). Of
the 11 indicted Clarks in my sample, 7 had their occupation listed as laborer,
thus illustrating the downward mobility of the medieval educated elite. There
was also sign of upward mobility. Cook
in the middle ages would likely not denote someone of particular wealth or
status. By 1600, however it was the surname of 1.3 percent of the richest
testators. Among the seven rich Cooks, five were described as Yeomen and one as
a Gentleman. Even medieval and early modern England was thus a very fluid
society, with families moving up and down the social scale across each
generation. (Clark, 2009)
References
Breen, M. (2004). The Koreans. Who They Are, What They Want, Where Their Future Lies,
St. Martin’s Press.
Britannica. (1998). ‘Japan’, vol. 22, p. 293
Clark, G. (2009). The indicted and
the wealthy: surnames, reproductive success, genetic selection and social class
in pre-industrial England.
http://www.econ.ucdavis.edu/faculty/gclark/Farewell%20to%20Alms/Clark%20-Surnames.pdf
Clark, G. (2007). A Farewell to Alms. A Brief Economic History of the World,
Princeton University Press, Princeton and Oxford
Moon, O. (1992) Confucianism and gender segregation
in Japan and Korea, in R. Goodman & K. Refsing. (eds) Ideology and Practice in Modern Japan, Routledge.
Unz, R. (2013). How Social Darwinism made modern
China, The American Conservative,
March 11
http://www.theamericanconservative.com/articles/how-social-darwinism-made-modern-china-248/